similar to the world’s largest prediction
market, Ireland-based Intrade.
“The request for comments was actually very well written and it’s clear
they understand a lot of the issues,”
Pennock says. Even if public prediction
markets for substantial sums are not
approved in the U.S., the markets offer
considerable promise for enterprise
planners who want the latest information on questions such as a product’s
likely launch date or revenue projections, and public policy forecasters,
who can design markets exempt from
CFTC oversight.
Growing opportunities in internal pri-vate-sector prediction markets are also
revealing divergent philosophies among
the markets’ designers. Many of the public markets feature price-adjustment
algorithms built around answering
discrete multiple-choice outcomes,
such as which candidate will win an
election or if a product will launch in
month x, y, or z. However, Mat Fogarty, CEO of prediction markets startup
Xpree, says enterprise clients need to
address questions expressed as continuous variables, such as a date range
in which a product will launch or how
many units will sell, and those markets
need to feature an intuitive interface
that encourages participation among
those without a great interest in financial or mathematic complexities. The
front end of these new prediction markets, as designed by Xpree, will feature
interfaces inspired by computer game
design, while the back end will replace
multiple-choice algorithms with automated market makers based on Bayes-ian probability, enabling participants
to place bets on a range of options.
David Pennock of Yahoo! at a “Prediction markets: tapping the Wisdom of crowds”
conference organized by Yahoo!’s technology Development Group.
forecasting events
The pioneering, modern public-policy
prediction market, the University of
Iowa’s Iowa Electronic Markets (IEM),
is now 21 years old and still offering
new events for traders to forecast. First
used in the 1988 U.S. presidential election, the IEM has offered markets on
congressional elections, federal monetary policy, and inspired university
colleagues to run a prediction market
on national influenza infection trends.
The IEM’s unique design also inspired
the latest corporate prediction market,
a virtual-money internal market operated by Google.
IEM steering committee member
Thomas Rietz, a professor of finance at
the university, says the aggregate zero-risk design of the IEM allows the markets to perfectly reflect the aggregate
forecast opinions of its participants. By
aggregate zero-risk, Rietz explains that
when a trader enters a particular bilateral (either/or) market, he or she must
buy one share of each choice, called a
bundle, for a total cost of $1. If the trader holds the bundle until the market
concludes, there is neither profit nor
gain. If the trader guesses the outcome
successfully, and sells the losing unit of
the bundle to another trader while the
market is running, he or she picks up
the original $1 bet plus whatever price
was agreed upon for the losing share
that was sold. If the trader chooses to
hold onto the loser and sell the eventual winner, however, they will incur
the $1 loss at payout time. At any given
the most visible
enterprise use of
prediction markets
is to help companies
improve product and
process development.
time, the number of eventual winning
shares and losing shares is equal and
held by the traders. So, the university
bears no counterparty risk and there
is no need to provide hedging margins
that irrationally affect outcomes.
“The price you would be willing to
buy or sell for today is your expectation
of its value in the future—the prices
can be directly interpreted as a forecast,” Rietz says. “In ordinary futures
markets, there is a long-lasting debate,
going back to John Maynard Keynes
in the 1930s, over whether prices can
legitimately be used as forecasts, and
it all hinges on whether or not people
demand a return or face a risk in aggregate when they’re investing in these
contracts.”
The enterprise markets are offering
intriguing design opportunities, as expressed by Xpree’s Fogarty, as well as
possible benefits beyond mining collective beliefs of what may make a successful product. The Google prediction
market, for example, was examined by
Bo Cowgill of Google, Justin Wolfers of
the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School of Business, and Eric Zitze-witz of Dartmouth College as a vehicle
for the way information flows within an
organization. Prediction markets, they
assert, provide employees with incentives for truthful revelation and can capture changes in opinion at a much higher frequency than surveys, allowing one
to track how information moves inside
an organization and how it responds
PhotograPh By daVid rout