ing a computer crime lawyer. Identifying the right people to contact directly
is much more expensive than using
a search engine. There has been no
real competitive response to the new
phenomenon of search engine advertising by the broadcast media. All this
means that Google and other search
engines can offer a uniquely strong
value proposition.
Google was not the first company to
price and display ads based on search
terms or “keywords” and to hold continuous automated auctions to price
the advertising of these keywords
(that was Goto.com in 1998). However, Google was the first large search
engine to use this model, and Yahoo
and MSN eventually followed. Google
assigns top ad placements to top bidders, but also uses a “quality score”
to sort out undesirable advertisers.
Besides ads based on keywords and
automated auctions, a third unusual
feature of search engine advertising is
that advertisers pay only when a user
clicks on their advertisement. This is
not original to Google either—it was
used by several different online publishers from 1996 on—but again this is
a much more targeted and measurable
advertising method than traditional
broadcast media advertising where
advertisers pay merely to be seen.
our methodology
In our research paper, we use data on
lawyers’ advertising decisions to illustrate that Google, Yahoo, and other
search engines’ ability to capitalize on
the long tail of advertising depends on
how easy it is to make a match between
advertiser and potential customer. This
in turn depends on two things: The
number of potential customers (fewer
customers = more wasted eyeballs) and
the difficulty of targeting niche customers using traditional broadcast media
or banner ads.
To examine how match difficulty affects advertiser decisions, we use data
from a lawyer Web site portal. The
data shows the ad prices that lawyers
looking to advertise on Google would
see for 139 different law-related keywords in April 2007. A typical example
of the variance in prices is that one
click on an ad in a top spot on Google
for “Truck accident attorney” in Boise, ID costs the advertiser about $12.
there has been no
real competitive
response to the
new phenomenon
of search engine
advertising from the
broadcast media.
In contrast, the same string of words
costs about $32 in Montgomery, AL.
“Employment attorney” costs about
$17 in Boise, but just $5 in Montgomery. We combine this data with information about the popularity of the
search terms and about restrictions
on lawyer behavior across locations.
We find that search engine advertising generates value through both
of the drivers of match difficulty: the
number of potential buyers and the
difficulty of targeting niche customers.
In particular, we show that, controlling
for location and search term, firms bid
more for keywords when there are fewer customers and therefore a greater
need for targeting. This result suggests
a possible reason for the price differences between Boise and Montgomery: when there are fewer searches for
a string, firms want a way to find these
niche customers and they bid the price
of that string higher.
establishing causation
Correlation does not establish causation. Higher global temperatures
are correlated with a lower incidence
of piracy on the high seas, but that
doesn’t mean that building pirate
ships will reduce global warming. For
empirical economists, one of their
biggest challenges is working out how
to establish causation from correlations in the data.
We found a raw correlation in the
data between a lack of searches and
higher prices, but of itself this does
not establish a causal link between
match difficulty and bids for search
engine ads. To establish a causal link,
we exploit a “natural experiment”
that results from the fact that lawyers’
activities are regulated at the state
level, by their state’s bar association.
These state regulations mean that
you can have two similar states, but in
one state lawyers are permitted to do
something, while in another state they
are not.
Specifically, many state bar associations prohibit “ambulance chasing” behavior. In 15 states, lawyers
are not permitted to contact clients
directly (electronically or in writing)
for a period following “personal injury or wrongful death.” This behavior is permitted in the other 35 states.
This restriction affects personal injury
lawyers, but it does not affect others.
When direct solicitation is banned,
it is more difficult for personal injury
lawyers to target clients. In the absence
of search engine advertising, these lawyers could only use broadcast media
to find clients. A key point is that the
restrictions do not affect the ability of
other lawyers to find clients; only personal injury lawyers are affected.
We show that when personal injury
lawyers are forbidden from directly
contacting clients, they are willing to
pay significantly more for search engine advertising, all else equal. By “all
else equal,” we mean we control for the
fact the keyword string “truck accident
attorney” generally costs more than the
keyword string “employment attorney”
and for the fact that search engine ads
in Montgomery cost slightly more than
search engine ads in Boise. Our analysis therefore compares whether personal injury keywords in locations with
restrictions cost more than other law
keywords in those locations, compared
to locations without restrictions. If we
exclude all other reasonable explanations for the price difference, then we
can legitimately attribute the cost difference to the presence or absence of
restrictions on lawyer behavior. We
will spare you the complicated statistical details—you can read the full paper
for those—but we worked out a way we
could legitimately connect the restrictions and keyword prices.
We find that personal injury keywords cost approximately $1 more per
click (or 11%) in places where directly
contacting clients is prohibited. By
making targeting more difficult, the
value of search engine advertising in-